ASEAN Beat

Cambodia’s Microfinance Industry: Why Bigger May Not Be Better

A closer look at an issue that has been in the spotlight recently.

Cambodia’s Microfinance Industry: Why Bigger May Not Be Better
Credit: Wikimedia Commons

An issue has been swirling around Cambodia’s microfinance circles for some months. Put simply, will poor Cambodians be able to use “movable assets” – motorbikes, cars, livestock or agricultural machinery, for example – as collateral on loans?

In some respects, the debate makes no difference; a far as I know, there is currently no law that prevents a microfinance institution (MFI) from accepting, say, a Honda Dream worth $800 as collateral for a loan of equal value.

“I’m not aware of any specific regulation that explicitly prohibits [or] allows MFIs from using movable assets as collateral,” Miguel Chanco, lead analyst in the ASEAN region for the Economist Intelligence Unit, told me.

The question, instead, is whether Cambodian MFIs should begin accepting such goods as collateral. According to Chanco, if they do, then they’ll be “catching up to what is a global trend.”

Indeed, many other countries’ MFIs readily accept them (though following the herd is rarely a good decider of policy). But at the moment there is a healthy amount of skepticism in Cambodia, especially by the country’s leading, and most trusted, MFIs.

Enjoying this article? Click here to subscribe for full access. Just $5 a month.

A November article by Hor Kimsay, a business reporter for the Phnom Penh Post, quoted Say Sony, senior vice president of Prasac Microfinance, one of Cambodia’s largest MFIs, as saying that the problem with movable assets is that they “can be quickly sold to dealers or pawn shops.” If this happens, the MFI is left saddling a defaulted debt and no collateral to collect.

Bun Mony, an adviser to the Cambodian Microfinance Association and CEO of Sathapana Bank, another MFI, however was quoted in the same article saying that “financial institutions have been trying to incorporate movable assets into their collateral portfolio because it would provide more opportunities for borrowers to take out loans,” as Kimsay phrased it. But he too admitted problems with doing just that.

Here, then, we find the pulse of the microfinance community in Cambodia: they want to start allowing movable assets as collateral but are rightly cautious of doing so. Indeed, most Cambodian MFIs temper their optimism by saying that a legal framework needs to be created to restrict what borrowers can do with their movable assets, and a registry to monitor their past activities. Again, this would be in line with most other countries. But how possible this is, however, is not known.

But even if it were possible – so that some of the pitfalls are adorned with safety nets – is it to be desired? The answer typically comes down one’s thoughts on the microfinance industry itself. According to Chanco, although the “MFI industry has grown rapidly over the past few years… there is still significant scope for growth.”

No doubt. But other experts say continued growth is to be avoided. Indeed, how much growth should be desired: Until half of the population is borrowing? Or all Cambodians?

The present-day figures are worrying. Cambodians collectively owed $3.1 billion to MFIs at the end of last year, according to a World Bank report, and 88 percent of borrowers live in impoverished rural areas. 28 percent of microfinance borrowers have multiple outstanding loan accounts, found a 2016 report by the Credit Bureau Cambodia, the country’s only credit agency.

Moreover, Kimsay wrote, “over 85 percent of these outstanding loans were designated as for personal finance – often to purchase the very same movable assets that consumers would hope to put down as collateral when applying for additional credit.” Applying for credit with the same goods bought on credit is rarely a good idea.

The Mimosa Project, an independent organization that researches microfinance indebtedness across the world, put out a circular last year which found “the size of the loans granted by [Cambodian] MFIs in the decade from 2004 to 2014 had grown at a rate four times the rate of the growth of incomes of the debtors receiving loans,” the Phnom Penh Post reported.  According to the circular: “When it comes to growth in loan sizes, there is simply no country that comes even close to Cambodia.”

In some ways it comes back to the epithet made famous by Muhammad Yunus, the Nobel Peace Prize-winning founder of Grameen bank, the Bangladeshi MFI that kick started the global “movement.” A few years ago he said that “credit is a fundamental human right.” Credit, however, is not a human right.  Other writers have pointed out how it is one example of the proliferation of new “rights” that effectively devalues other human rights.

More simply, though, just because someone wants a loan it doesn’t mean they should be allowed one. Time will tell if Cambodia’s microfinance industry is as stable as some experts claim. Few predict the bubble busting in anytime soon – though few predicted the global financial crisis. (Economists, like philosophers, tend to be left at Minerva’s owl flying away from them.)

Enjoying this article? Click here to subscribe for full access. Just $5 a month.

But another consideration deserves some attention: What is the relationship between microfinance and politics? This issue arose in March when the Cambodian government, through the National Bank of Cambodia, imposed an interest rate cap on microfinance loans. The move was panned by most analysts who thought it was unhelpful intervention and regulation.

But not everyone was so critical. Ou Virak, founder of the Future Forum think tank, is a commentator who eschews the “anything the government does is inherently bad” line of thinking. In March, he told me:

My view is that it should have come much sooner. Microfinance, as once a noble idea, has become a grand scheme to try to make as much money as possible, from the greatest number of people as possible. Given that the poor lack options and tend to naturally be in desperation (at least so it seems to them most of the time), microfinance has been a catch phrase for lenders to make big returns with little accountability to whether those loans should have been lent in the first place. Without regulations and enforcement, in a very sad sense, microfinance is a formalized scheme for loan sharks.

It’s more fundamental than that, however. Look long enough and one can see a libertarian tinge that pervades the microfinance world. A few years back, after saying he doesn’t give money to beggars, Yunus was quoted:

I think that rich countries have fallen into this trap with welfare systems where able-bodied humans are paid to sit around and do nothing. This is a system that produces zombies. By giving money to beggars you have the same response. It is the system, not your conscience, that needs reforming.

To some extent, I understand where Yunus is coming from. Most poor countries are unlikely, or incapable, of introducing welfare systems like those found in rich nations. So, an alternative is needed. But shouldn’t welfare systems at least be the main aspiration and alternatives the fallback? Yunus, clearly, thinks not and, perhaps, for ideological reasons, not just practical ones.

“Yunus implicitly argues that non-state actors should be obligated to make the right to credit meaningful because of the state’s incapacity to fulfill the right,” one academic wrote. Here, one finds a sophistry in the microfinance worldview: It is the responsibility of the state to ensure the poor can access credit, ostensibly for people remove themselves from poverty, but the same state is incapable of (or shouldn’t be, for some) doing this itself.

Microfinance can often combine the worst of the 19th century’s idea of the “deserving poor” with the worst of the 21st century’s nihilism on the role of governments. Perhaps it is overly optimistic of me, but don’t Cambodians have the right to demand more action from their government, rather than more means to take out loans? Indeed, one of the main political debates at the moment is how much the Cambodian government should do to provide public services (the country’s two main political parties frequently spar on this issue with the opposition claiming the government needs to introduce more social services for the poor.)

Microfinance should be the last resort for the poor, not the first solution. One should be hoping for a time when fewer, not more, Cambodians need short-term loans. And, in the ideal world, MFIs should be working towards their own demise, not to even larger portfolios.